Healthcare: Sick In America.
This three part series attempts to answer some of the most pressing and complicated questions about healthcare in the United States. As one of the only industrialized nations without government funded, universal healthcare, there is a natural tension between providing patient-centered care and trying to turn a profit. We look at the history of healthcare and coverage and why the United States treats medical care as a fringe benefit rather than a human right.
AT A GLANCE:

Part One: U.S. Healthcare: America’s Hypocritical Oath.
Summary: Today, we’re doing some level setting on healthcare in the U.S.—a long requested topic. We navigate this unf*cking based on direct queries from the Unf*ckers, creating a baseline that helps establish a foundation for related features down the road and an understanding of the moving parts and shared language for the challenges we face. Stay tuned, as next week we’re going to delve deep into the Affordable Care Act.
“Fringe Benefit.” That’s how healthcare came to be regarded in the United States. Lumped in with meal perks, an extra day off, maybe a brand spanking new company car. The very idea that healthcare is even associated with employment should be problematic enough. Let alone the fact that it’s considered a fringe benefit instead of a natural right.
We’re going to do some level setting this week, then follow up next week and drill into problematic parts of The Affordable Care Act (ACA). It’s not going to be a series, per se, but the topic is just so overwhelming that it would be an exercise in absurdity to try and unf*ck the entire thing in one go.
So this is one of those baseline conversations that helps us establish a foundation for related features down the road, an understanding of the moving parts and shared language for the challenges we face. But it’s time to begin in earnest, and some of the measures incorporated into the Inflation Reduction Act offer a reasonable jumping off point for us to enter the fray.
I don’t think there are any huge ah-ha moments that will knock you on your ass. That said, it was an important exercise, personally, because it forced me to think about the moving parts of the healthcare industry more critically.
It’s also one of the most requested topics by our audience. In fact, for this episode, most of the resources I’m relying on came from Unf*ckers. In terms of level setting, I actually want to begin with a handful of requests to help frame the inquiry. These questions helped organize my path as I plodded through some insightful books and articles, demonstrating once again that this community is bright and curious and our process is truly collaborative.
For example, here are some questions posed by Unf*cker ‘Jean S.’ a while back:
-
Why is healthcare so expensive and complicated?
-
Why does this country spend the most for poor outcomes relative to other countries?
-
And perhaps the most impossible and intriguing question; isn’t it immoral to make a profit off of sick people?
‘James M.,’ a listener who has spent more than 30 years in healthcare, suggested that we break up the industry into several topics saying, “The U.S. does not have a health system. It has multiple organizations seeking to maintain their mission by being profitable or maintaining their bond rating and having a surplus.”
One of the crucial resources I dug into for this, and undoubtedly for every future essay, is one that James recommended titled The Social Transformation of American Medicine, by Paul Starr. If you’re in the field, my guess is you already know of it. It came out a few decades ago, but it was a Pulitzer Prize winning book that remains relevant to this day and contains updates to the original. James suggested that we examine the disparate distribution of care, how professionals are trained and the differences between employer funded insurance and the Great Society programs that care for the aged and indigent. We’ll hit on some of these.
He then recommended that we separate Big Pharma from the discussion to set it on its own, specifically as it related to the role of Pharmacy Benefit Managers, or “PBMs.” And on this, I must profess some professional jealousy. One of the very first folders I created for UNFTR was titled PBMs. One of my best friends who worked in the industry had given me chapter and verse on these companies, and their existence is beyond scandalous.
Strangely, there’s precious little written about their role in the world, which makes it hard to research, but tantalizing to cover. But I kept kicking that can down the road. So, while I was on vacation, I revived my notes and figured it was a good place to start. Then I opened my pod app and went to one of my favorite pods called Congressional Dish, by Jennifer Briney, only to find that she just did a remarkable episode on PBMS in July. My hat’s off on this one. Check it out when you have a chance. It’s episode 255, and it’s extremely well done, as all of her shows are. I digress.
‘Phil S.’ sent a detailed email to us a while back, and I have to give him props for the thought that went into it. Phil segmented the topic into six distinct categories:
-
Our disproportionate outcomes as it relates to wealth, ethnicity and disability.
-
The uniqueness of our employer based insurance system.
-
The politicization of healthcare.
-
The “fallacies, perverse incentives and opportunities for exploitative financial fuckery that would make Milton Friedman harder than Matt Gaetz at a quinceañera.” (Unf*ckers really know how to get to my heart.) Among the examples he offers is “inelasticity of demand among patients… a complete lack of price transparency reinforced by mysterious chargemaster lists… costs distorted by insurance companies… and asymmetrical power dynamics often exacerbated by the racial and gender dynamics that are too often present.”
-
Consolidation and corporatization in medicine to maximize profits at the expense of quality, personalization and compassion of care.
-
A dysfunctional system with no incentive to keep people well.
And one more. Unf*cker ‘Sam E.’ who offered a basic and biting truth: we need to improve the system to have more people not in need of healthcare than in need of it. “In our supposed free market model, healthcare is a self actualizing industry.” Sam sent in a long and well reasoned letter that ends with another doozy. How can we transform the system to focus our efforts on quality of life over length of life.
That’s just a sampling of the requests and direction we’ve received regarding healthcare over the past year. Nearly all of us come in contact with the healthcare system on an almost daily basis. Perhaps you’re ill or care for a loved one who is. If you’re healthy and employed, you might not think about it, but your compensation involves some sort of complex deductions that impact your take home pay and coverage should you be in need of it. Maybe you’re without insurance, and it haunts your subconscious knowing that you’re one catastrophic event away from bankruptcy, or worse. Whatever the circumstance, medical care in the United States is its own singular stress point that we experience differently than every other industrialized country in the world.
Like I said, too much to bite off in a single go. So the challenge is how exactly to begin. In that spirit, there’s no time like the present.
Chapter One
A Bandaid on an Open Wound
“This law that I’m about to sign finally delivers on a promise that Washington has made for decades to the American people… I got here as a 29-year old kid, and we were promising to make sure that Medicare would have the power to negotiate lower drug prices back then… Seniors are going to pay less for prescription drugs… we’re putting a cap, a maximum of $2,000 per year on prescription drug costs no matter what the reason for those prescriptions are… This is a godsend. A godsend to many families. And long overdue.” -President Joe Biden on signing the Inflation Reduction Act.
Let’s be optimistic for a moment and take Uncle Joe at his word. The Inflation Reduction Act shores up some crucial gaps in the ACA.
In a New York Times op-ed, Larry Levitt from the Kaiser Family Foundation called the medical provisions in the Act, “The biggest health reform initiative since passage of the Affordable Care Act… and the single biggest political loss the drug industry has sustained. Big Pharma is no longer invincible, which could embolden future efforts to expand the scope of the drug-pricing restraints.”
I think it’s a fair statement—if not a sadly painful one—considering almost nothing has happened to improve coverage since the ACA. Caps on insulin as well as out of pocket charges for seniors and the ability for Medicare to negotiate drug prices hit directly at some of the fatal flaws of the ACA that placed many plans out of reach and left Medicare woefully inadequate for many seniors.
But even Levitt acknowledges that, “As popular as their platform will be, its reach has limits. Drug-pricing restraints will not apply immediately or to everyone, and drugs account for less than 10% of health spending.”
So, we have to contextualize this, even if it pisses in the nation’s cornflakes. Yes, these provisions will be a “godsend,” as Uncle Joe referred to them, to many seniors. That’s a really, really good thing. But, on balance, because this bill is being presented as somewhat of a capstone to Obamacare and the Democrats are doing a victory lap, there’s a sense of finality to the whole thing. Like everything’s fixed. But it’s not. In fact, these provisions, while certainly an improvement on the existing healthcare infrastructure, simply codify the nation’s Rube Goldberg system of laws and agents who profit from a system designed to line the pockets of institutions. They are, dare I say… pissing in the ocean to warm it up.
This bill is an acknowledgement that the fight for universal healthcare is over, as far as Democrats are concerned. And that’s a troubling realization. Both the Senate and the House voted entirely along party lines, with King of Maine and Sanders of Vermont siding with Democrats and Vice President Harris casting the tie-breaking vote. I get it. This bill was really about salvaging as many pieces of Build Back Better that impacted climate change reversal as Joe Manchin would allow.
Speaking of Joe Manchin. If any doubt remained as to whether or not this was his bill, witness the moment after President Biden affixes his signature to the bill. Biden reaches across Senator Schumer to hand the pen to a surprised Manchin. A couple of ways to interpret this. One, Joe is a better politician than most give him credit for. Another is that it symbolizes an acquiescence of sorts. To the old ways of doing business. This is D.C. We do things a certain way here. The good ol’ boy way.
Manchin and Schumer’s respective staff hashed out the details in private, so the story goes. Folks like Sinema were brought along with the promise that Wall Street would be protected. So would the insurance companies. And the fossil fuel industry. While I could certainly go on, there’s someone with far more standing and experience who would do a much better job of explaining where this all falls short. Buckle up for Bernie. Here are a few excerpts from his speech on the floor of the Senate:
“Given this is the last reconciliation bill that we will be considering this year, it is the only opportunity that we have to do something significant for the American people that requires only 50 votes and that cannot be filibustered.”
“Does this bill make it easier for workers who want to join a union to be able to do so, or will they continue to be attacked by their employers, making it hard to form a union? No. This bill does nothing to address that reality.”
“Does this bill extend the $300 a month per child tax credit that was so important to millions of families last year? Does it address that issue?”
“Does this bill do anything to help us create a rational, cost-effective health care system which guarantees healthcare for all as a human right, something that every other major country on earth does? No. This bill does nothing to address the extraordinary healthcare crisis that we face.”
“Is there anything in the currently written bill to expand Medicare to do what some 75, 80% of the American people think we should do? And that is to expand Medicare to cover dental care for seniors, hearing aids, and eyeglasses? No. This bill doesn’t touch that at all.”
“Under this legislation, Medicare for the first time would be able to negotiate with the pharmaceutical industry to lower drug prices. That’s the good news. The bad news is that we will not see the impact of these negotiated prices until 2026. Four years from now. Why? Got me. I don’t know.”
“When it comes to reducing the price of prescription drugs on Medicare, we don’t have to reinvent the wheel. We could simply require Medicare to pay no more for prescription drugs than the VA pays. End of discussion. A rather simple solution.”
“In terms of the Affordable Care Act, this legislation will extend subsidies for some 13 million Americans who have private health insurance plans as a result of the ACA over the next three years. Without this provision, millions of Americans would see their premiums skyrocket, and some 3 million Americans could lose their health insurance altogether. This is a good provision. I support it. But let us not kid ourselves. The $64 billion dollar cost of this provision will go directly into the pockets of private health insurance companies that made over $60 billion dollars in profit last year and pay their CEOs exorbitant compensation packages.”
Bernie spends the next ten minutes eviscerating the giveaways to the fossil fuel industry and how poorly crafted some of the renewable energy incentives are. But, in these statements, you can hear a dejected Bernie Sanders, still a seemingly lone voice in the progressive wilderness, almost coming to grips with the fact that this bill might not be the beginning of something special, but the last blown opportunity of his career.
Sorry to be so fatalistic about this, because there really are some things to celebrate. But, when you dig in a little deeper, it feels like a pyrrhic victory of sorts. And, because it solves important pain points for a critical voting bloc of seniors and strengthens the position of insurers, hospitals, drug companies, manufacturers, providers and lobbyists, it feels like the book has been closed on universal healthcare. Again. For now.
Chapter Two
The Long Arm of Milton Friedman
In the next chapter, we’re going to talk about the giant forces that move the healthcare industry. It’s important to understand that spending on healthcare is now 20% of our nation’s GDP. There are several ways to parse GDP data, but nearly every method drives to the same conclusion when you tally it up. It’s our biggest sector. And it makes a lot of people a lot of money.
There was a time, perhaps a couple of occasions throughout history, when a move toward nationalized health care was more conceivable. When it was part of the Bull Moose platform under Teddy Roosevelt in 1912. As part of FDR’s package of reforms prior to the war. Under Truman just after FDR passed. LBJ came the farthest with Medicare and Medicaid. But since then, it has steadily moved out of reach.
Single payer has always faced opposition. In the beginning, it was from rather unlikely places in hindsight. But over time, the forces have become almost insurmountable. Before we dig into just how big these forces are in the next chapter, let’s have a philosophical discussion.
As usual, the countervailing narrative to a single payer approach is best illustrated by none other than Milton Friedman.
Friedman was prolific until the end, including a paper on healthcare published in 2001 just five years prior to his death. It’s worth expending some energy on this because his unerring dedication to the free market is evident, even in the sound logic of the paper that drives him to a most illogical conclusion. Let’s start with some hardcore logic from uncle fucknugget’s paper.
“No third party is involved when we shop at a supermarket. We pay the supermarket clerk directly: the same for gasoline for our car, clothes for our back, and so on down the line. Why, by contrast, are most medical payments made by third parties? The answer for the United States begins with the fact that medical care expenditures are exempt from the income tax if, and only if, medical care is provided by the employer. If an employee pays directly for medical care, the expenditure comes out of the employee’s after-tax income.
“If the employer pays for the employee’s medical care, the expenditure is treated as a tax-deductible expense for the employer and is not included as part of the employee’s income subject to income tax. That strong incentive explains why most consumers get their medical care through their employers or their spouses’ or their parents’ employer. In the next place, the enactment of Medicare and Medicaid in 1965 made the government a third-party payer for persons and medical care covered by those measures. We are headed toward completely socialized medicine—and, if we take indirect tax subsidies into account, we’re already halfway there.”
Okay. So let’s pause and reflect on these basic suppositions for a moment.
One thing uncle fartknocker was very good at was boiling things down to consumable examples that make sense in everyday life. Let’s start with the correlation between services such as shopping for gasoline, clothes and groceries. It’s tempting to just let this pass because medical services can theoretically be boiled down into goods and services. But what this ignores is the variability of health care needs and diagnoses.
You don’t get a second opinion at a gas station. And shopping for clothes isn’t a life or death decision. The clerk at the store is delivering a predetermined quantity of items at a price often set by bureaucratic institutions that Friedman so loves to hate. There’s nothing free and floating about gas prices. The store clerk has no influence over where the cotton was harvested for a shirt. And food prices are negotiated well in advance on global markets unseen and hardly understood by the person at the checkout counter. No clerk went to four years of college, another four years of medical school and two years of a residency to qualify them to make a crucial shopping decision that might alter the course of your life.
So, no. They’re not the same.
But he does make an interesting point about third parties, which we’ll get to later. More to his point regarding tax deductions, this actually explains a great deal of the rise of third parties in determining costs and coverage of medical care in the United States.
Now, we’ll return to Milton in a moment. But, to address this point, I actually want to turn to Paul Starr’s Social Transformation of Medicine to explain what he calls “the accommodation of insurance” in America compared to the European model that developed simultaneously and very differently. Bear with me on this one. It’s a long passage, but it eloquently describes how and why the two paths ultimately diverged:
“The original European model began with the industrial working class and emphasized income maintenance; from that base, it expanded in both its coverage of the population and its range of benefits. The original Progressive proposals for compulsory health insurance had shared much of this orientation, except that the American Progressives had a distinctive interest in reorganizing medical care on more efficient and rational lines. The defeat of that early conception meant there was no prior institutional structure for health insurance when the middle class encountered its problems of paying for hospital costs during the 1920s and when the hospitals encountered problems meeting their expenses during the Depression.
“So, instead of an insurance system founded originally to relieve the economic problems of workers, America developed an insurance system originally concerned with improving the access of middle-class patients to hospitals and of hospitals to middle-class patients. The Progressive interest in group practice, capitation payment, and incentives for prevention was rejected, and an insurance system developed under the control of the hospitals and doctors that sought to buttress the existing forms of organization. This was the basis for the accommodation of private insurance.”
So, from inception, we can see a couple of different tensions. If we take Milton Friedman’s view on the world, no system should have developed. Any barrier between patient and provider should be eliminated. Depression or no depression. The market will work it out. That’s… well, that’s one view. The European model, that was expressly rejected in America, was to protect the patient. The American model was designed to protect the hospital.
The idea being that if the provider is secure, then access to care is as well.
There are arguments to be made on both sides of this equation, and I think it’s helpful to understand where these ideas were originally formulated. This one question—whether the patient or the provider is the foundation of the healthcare system—ultimately determined the trajectory of the entire system moving forward. We chose to build around the system itself rather than the patient.
Now, let’s go back to uncle dickcheese’s contention that government incentives in the American system favored the growth of private insurers, whether intentional or not. On this, he is 100% right. Once again, here’s Starr to clarify:
“The health insurance system was set up in a highly regressive fashion: first, because it was based on employment; second, because of the practices of community and experience rating; and third, because of the favorable tax treatment of private insurance. (The Internal Revenue Code of 1954 confirmed that employers’ contributions to health benefit plans were tax exempt; indirectly, this exemption constituted a massive subsidy to people who had private insurance policies.) In leaving out millions of Americans, the insurance system actually worsened their position because of the inflationary effect that insurance had on the cost of medical care.”
Let’s stay in this pivotal period to tease out some of the early detractors of a universal system in the U.S. because they might surprise you.
So we’re talking about the ‘40s and ‘50s. During and after the Second World War.
Very much in the grips and immediate aftermath of the Great Depression.
The beginning of the Red Scare.
And the precipice of revolutions in medicine from vaccines to medical devices.
Prior to this period, healthcare was almost feudal. Infection and disease worsened by the economic crisis of the Depression. Almost all research was privately funded by wealthy patricians. As Starr notes, “In the early 1900s, the budget of the Rockefeller Institute alone was many times larger than federal expenditures for medical research.” It was understood that there were multiple therapeutic uses for penicillin, but access to it was extremely limited. It might have been a medical wonder, but if no one could get their hands on it, then it really didn’t matter.
So Roosevelt set about supercharging the industry. Scientists were smuggled into the United States from Germany after the war, and Roosevelt knew that psychological and physical ailments brought on by the war would be a major concern. And so the money came rolling in.
When the industry was coming of age, and before it was beset by professional lobbies and corporate interests, there were other forces at play that aligned against a nationalized health insurance system. Roosevelt was out of runway on domestic policies near the end of the war, as the nation turned its attention to post war economic concerns. The Truman administration attempted to pick up the mantle of reform to continue the legacy with a national healthcare model, but he ran into interference from the outset.
As hard as Truman worked to codify a version of national coverage, the first line of defense was actually physicians. As Stephen Brill writes in America’s Bitter Pill:
“The AMA spent what in 1949 was an astounding $1.5 million to campaign against the plan, labeling it socialized medicine that would be the key to the arch of a socialist state, which would destroy doctors’ independent relationships with their patients and lead to doctors becoming government employees.”
There are a few factors at play here. First off, they were tapping into very real public fears surrounding socialism in the post-war era. It cannot be overstated just how popular a selling point this is, no matter how much sense socialized programs make. Americans have been so indoctrinated against any hint of socialism that it persists as a bogeyman to this day.
Closer to home for the doctors themselves was the fact that they were making real money and that they weren’t about to have terms dictated to them by a bunch of government bureaucrats.
Remember, during the Great Depression and even prior to that, doctors weren’t paid all that well. And, in hard times, they were last on the list. So, when private insurance through employer sponsored programs coincided with a population boom and advances in medicine and outcomes, the profession grew up rapidly. And it wasn’t about to give back the gains it had made in a very short period of time.
The other roadblock for a universal coverage scheme in the U.S. was actually put up by unions. Sounds counterintuitive, but employer sponsored healthcare coverage was a union invention. One of the greatest perks ever conceived, in fact. If the government suddenly offered competitive benefits to the entire population, a critical bargaining element that made union membership special would suddenly be nullified.
Back to Brill’s book America’s Bitter Pill:
“The reason the unions were against government-supplied health care had to do with a quiet decision made during World War II by Franklin Roosevelt’s National War Labor Board, a panel he appointed to enforce wartime wage and price controls. In 1943, the board ruled that fringe benefits—including health insurance—were not subject to wage controls, which prohibited an employer seeking to encourage workers to join or stay at his company from enticing them with higher pay. Under the board’s ruling, an employer could lure workers by offering to pay for health insurance, to be supplied by what would soon become a flood of insurance companies flocking into the new market. The decision motivated unions to oppose government intervention.”
I know we all want to point fingers and know who’s to blame today. And there’s plenty of blame and anger to go around. But it’s important to nail down our history and understand when the ball started rolling and who gave it the first push downhill.
Chapter Three
Stakeholders and Cost Drivers
Alright. So let’s talk about who’s to blame today. Because that was then and this is now. Why has this issue become so intractable? We know the talking points by heart from the Progressive movement:
-
We’re the only industrialized nation in the world without universal healthcare.
-
Healthcare is a right not a privilege.
-
We pay the most for healthcare with some of the worst outcomes among OECD countries.
-
Insurance companies and Big Pharma are raking in billions of dollars in profits.
Now, we’ve established that healthcare writ large comprises 20% of our nation’s GDP. Another way to look at that is there are a lot of people who depend on this industry to make a living. It’s not all going into shareholder pockets, right?
So, let’s talk about who exactly is at the table to try and understand who is actually negotiating how care is paid for and administered in this country:
-
Medical device manufacturers
-
Labor and service unions
-
Insurance providers
-
Family doctors
-
Nurses
-
Surgeons
-
The Catholic Church
-
Drug companies
-
Law firms
-
Non profit hospitals
-
For profit hospitals
-
Plastic surgeons
-
Cosmetic surgeons
-
Anesthesiologists
-
Pharmacy benefit managers
-
Pharmacies
-
Ambulance drivers
-
Tanning bed manufacturers (not a joke)
-
Vitamin and supplement manufacturers
-
And on and on…
Seriously. This is a partial list. And for every category mentioned, there is a big time lobby behind them.
Attempts have been made to deliver what they call “patient centric” care, particularly in the ACA. For example, tying hospital reimbursements to outcomes. Clawbacks on payments if patients are readmitted for issues after being discharged. Some financial considerations, such as the ones in the Inflation Reduction Act, that attempt to ease the burden on certain vulnerable populations.
But, for the most part, discussions surrounding reform revolve around ways to contain costs and increase access. In fact, those were the only guiding principles behind the deliberations surrounding Obamacare.
Before we get there, let’s drill into a few numbers to illustrate the sheer scope of financial incentives for private companies that are baked into our current system. Here are 12 companies, three major ones representing four distinct industries under the healthcare umbrella. Four companies and their annual profits for fiscal year 2021, to give you an idea of just how much money is at stake in the current system.
Medical Devices
-
Medtronic, manufacturer of an array of surgical products, from diabetes and cardiovascular to urology and orthopedics, produced a net income of $5 billion last year.
-
Abbott Labs, producer of consumer brands like Pedialyte and Similac, and scores of professional diagnostic tools and medicines, threw off $7.6 billion in profit in 2021.
-
And Stryker, manufacturer of everything from beds and PPE to surgical tools and medical implants, made a $3.4 billion profit.
-
And Theranos…just kidding.
For Profit Hospitals
-
HCA Healthcare Inc., based in Tennessee, has more than 200 hospitals and 2,000 care centers that produced a $7.7 billion profit in 2021.
-
California’s Kaiser Permanente hospital system, one of the oldest in the country, threw off $8.1 billion last year.
-
And Universal Health Services, headquartered in Pennsylvania, has over 89,000 employees and threw off $1 billion.
Insurance Companies
-
UnitedHealth Group posted $17 billion in profit for 2021.
Big Pharma
-
Pfizer had a big year, partly because of COVID, but it’s a perennial monster that threw off a whopping $22 billion in profit in 2021.
-
Merck made $7 billion last year.
-
And AbbVie, maker of the wildly successful arthritis drug Humira, also had a banner year with $11.5 billion in profit.
Total it all up, and that’s $99 billion in profit.
$99 billion in profit, split between 12 major healthcare companies representing Big Pharma, for profit hospitals, medical devices and health insurance. There are more than 2,000 brand name pharmaceutical companies in the United States. 6,000 hospitals. 6,500 medical device companies. And over 1,000 health insurance companies. Thousands of companies, millions of employees. 20% of GDP. When you begin to digest the magnitude of the economic impact contained within this sector of the economy, the resistance makes a lot more sense.
Chapter Four
Bring it home, Max.
A lot of thoughts on this one. Some, we’ll clarify further next week and in related essays down the road. But, I want to return to Milton Friedman first, before we close this chapter.
Friedman concludes that a voucher system is the only way to go. To completely eliminate any friction between provider and patient. Medical savings accounts, to be specific. As he says, “Medical savings accounts… would voucherize Medicare and Medicaid.” His theory is that if government incentives like tax breaks disappear for employers and the government gets out of insurance, with the exception of catastrophic care, then the market will resolve itself.
Friedman’s vision once again delivers us back to the industrial revolution days when men were men and took charge of their own lives. That time in our history when there were 60 million of us, each with a life expectancy of 48. But he goes there as well and credits—get this—“improvements in diet, housing, clothing, and so on generated by greater affluence, better garbage collection and disposal, the provision of purer water, and other governmental public health measures,” for extending the lives of Americans.
It’s hard to tell if he’s punking us or not. Everything he credits for extending our lives is the direct result of government programs and interventions into the so-called free market to restrain corporations from doing the most harm they possibly can.
Then he goes on to say that, “In terms of holding down cost, one-payer directly administered government systems, such as exist in Canada and Great Britain, have a real advantage over our mixed system. As the direct purchaser of all or nearly all medical services, they are in a monopoly position.”
Importantly, he sees this as anti-competitive and resulting in the suppression of physician wages. Of course, he doesn’t mention that general practitioners, surgeons, nurses and family doctors earn more on average in Canada than in the United States. Only top surgical specialists in the U.S. earn so much more than Canada or the UK that it skews the numbers. So, no. Countries with socialized medicine value the medical field more than we do. What they don’t have are outrageously profitable companies that rob the system of capital that could otherwise go to saving consumers money.
But, as I’ve said before when evaluating motives, Milton Friedman was not a bad person with ill intentions. In fact, he concludes his paper saying, “The first question asked of a patient entering a hospital might once again become ‘What’s wrong?’ not ‘What’s your insurance.’” Like almost everything else he tackles, Friedman has the right inputs and a well intentioned output, but something happens in the middle when he looks at it all, because he can only evaluate the data through the free market lens. And in so many key areas of life, the free market simply does not apply because there are human factors that intervene to infect the data.
Okay, so he’s been dead for 20 years. Other than my obsession with him, why bring him into the conversation, right?
Because his concepts continue to carry a lot of weight. Take, for example, voucherizing healthcare. That remains one of the most popular talking points among conservatives. John McCain ran against Obama on this premise. Paul Ryan and Mitch McConnell tried to overthrow Obamacare when they took over Congress under the belief that a voucher system would be better. Donald Trump hinted at it but, as we know, he never had a repeal and replace plan. Because this shit is hard.
The real truth in the Republican Party is that they are celebrating the healthcare wins of the Obama and Biden administrations just as much as the Democrats. Because their donors are all the same.
When the Democrats blamed Kyrsten Sinema for eliminating the carried interest tax loophole in the Inflation Reduction Act, I just laughed. She’s a convenient foil. No politician outside of the Progressive Caucus members who really, really get this stuff understands the correlation between this provision and literally everything else in our economy.
Those profits we talked about before? The $99 billion dollars in net income last year from only 12 out of about 15,000 healthcare companies in the United States came from public companies. Companies that have grown so large through unstoppable mergers and acquisitions. Corporations that control entire regions of the nation’s healthcare. Drug companies that dangle the promise of extended life in the first three seconds of an ad, followed by 57 seconds of disclaimers. But only if you’re lucky enough to have the insurance. Preventive care?
Fuhgeddaboudit.
Those big public companies that throw off massive profits aren’t building care systems around patients. They’re building systems around shareholders. And who are these shareholders? Unf*ckers know. Officially 90% of all stocks are owned by the top 10% of income earners in the nation. They tell you that it’s pensioners and old people. 401k participants and grandmas. They’re lying. It’s the richest 10%.
When economists talk about profits, they call it “surplus capital.” Money made beyond what labor was paid to create a product or service.
Marxists call this wage theft.
Modern capitalists call it a human right, and they have the Supreme Court decision to prove it.
So which is it? Well, the answer, in my opinion, comes from Unf*cker ‘Jean’s’ opening query:
“Isn’t it immoral to make a profit off of sick people?”
That very simple question has a very straightforward answer. Yes. It is immoral. And, if we start with this premise, it changes every input, every data point, every next question.
From beginning to end, we built a system to care for the top 10% of the nation.
The Inflation Reduction Act adds more nails to the barn door during the hurricane.
The answers will always be wrong if the question is.
Here endeth the lesson.

Part Two: This Healthcare Is Killing Us: The perpetual cycle of money madness.
Chapter One
Understanding the scope of healthcare.
The New York Times dropped an article this week detailing the rising U.S. mortality rate. A fall that Dr. Steven Woolf, director emeritus of the Center on Society and Health at Virginia Commonwealth University called “historic.”
From the article:
“It was the largest reduction in life expectancy in the United States over the course of a two-year period since the early 1920s, when life expectancy fell to 57.2 in 1923. That drop-off may have been related to high unemployment and suicide rates during an earlier recession, as well as a steep increase in mortality among nonwhite men and women.
“Although the U.S. health care system is among the best in the world, Americans suffer from what experts have called “the U.S. health disadvantage,” an amalgam of influences that erode well-being, Dr. Woolf said.
“These include a fragmented, profit-driven health care system; poor diet and a lack of physical activity; and pervasive risk factors such as smoking, widespread access to guns, poverty and pollution. The problems are compounded for marginalized groups by racism and segregation, he added.”
I want to thank the Times for the proper introduction to our second healthcare episode as we chip away at the American system, how it compares to others around the world and the unique challenges we face in repairing it.
There’s a general belief that the United States has the most inefficient and disparate level of healthcare among what is known as The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Unless you’re filthy rich, in which case our care is wonderful. But I digress. For clarity of process, OECD is just one of the acronym organizations that we’re relying on when contrasting systems, structures and outcomes across the world. And that’s a good place to pick back up on the topic and frame the discussion.
In terms of measurement, OECD nations aren’t the be all and end all. To start, this is an organization of 38 member nations representing Europe, the Americas and Pacific region. Naturally, there are a vast number of countries that aren’t represented. The purpose of using OECD nations as a benchmark is because the organization itself is a collection of countries with so-called market economies. There are corollary OECD working groups that draw data from non-participating or full member countries, but that goes a little further than necessary for our purposes.
I bring it up because the BRIC economies for example—Brazil, Russia, India and China—aren’t full members, but that doesn’t mean their systems and outcomes aren’t relevant to us. Like, it might be surprising to know that China has a market based insurance system. It works differently and nearly every citizen has what’s called Basic Medical Insurance, or BMI, but it’s important to understand there is parity in other places we don’t think of off the bat.
The other comparative area to explore is with respect to outcomes. And, as I mentioned in the prior episode, we’re relying on World Health Organization data because it has the most consistent 50 point benchmarking strategy over the longest period of time. Those are enough individual data points to be statistically meaningful, and the key element is, of course, a consistent trend line.
Assuming I’ve covered my ass enough, let’s get on with it.
All of which is to say, there’s no perfect way to go about this. The inputs and measurements matter. And no one country, just like no one patient, is the same. But if we’re to rely on global metrics, there are a few unmistakable signs that we’re on the wrong path here in the United States. Beyond the emotion and the politics, we have major structural issues. Not the least of which is spending for care per capita.
Despite spending the most per capita on healthcare by a wide margin, we have comparable to less favorable outcomes. (We’ll talk more about that a bit later.) And outcomes and satisfaction are two different things. In terms of satisfaction, how satisfied overall a country’s citizens are with healthcare access, affordability and quality, the U.S. really has a problem. When you compare it to a country like France, which regularly ranks at the top of the list in terms of satisfaction, we spend double the amount per citizen. These are the gaps that drive policy makers and medical professionals nuts. And yet, when policy measures are introduced, we seem incapable of asking the hard questions. Unless it’s Bernie.
But other politicians, like this guy running for office in 2008, recognized the problem using this very comparison:
“We spend more than other advanced nations on healthcare by a substantial amount. We spend about 50% more than France does on healthcare and yet they’ve got universal healthcare. A doctor will come to your house at 3 o’clock in the morning and prescribe you for what you need and you get it for free. Now, yes, you’re paying higher taxes, but what’s also happening though is they get a much more efficient system because they have more prevention and, as a consequence, regular check-ups, regular screenings, they save money and improve quality over the long-term.” -Barack Obama on the campaign trail in 2008.
What’s fascinating about this particular excerpt is how little of the candidate’s understanding of the problem actually made it into the proposed White House solution once he became President.
Because precious little actually came from the Obama White House.
Because it wasn’t his plan.
Because he didn’t have a plan.
The plan that is today known as Obamacare was originally known as Romneycare in Massachusetts and had, in fact, been circulating in conservative policy circles as early as 1989 by a Heritage Foundation associate named Stuart Butler. In fact, here’s Butler explaining the essential part of what he was trying to solve:
“It seems to me that until we get serious about a budget in the publicly supported—through tax or direct expenditures—the publicly supported parts of the healthcare system, we will never exert the pressure to make the tough decisions on how we actually get healthcare that we really need to do.”
Again, we’ll get to this when we talk about how the ACA came to be, but I want to recognize some of the language as we continue here. That direct tax he’s talking about is what became the so-called mandate. You know, that thing that caused Republicans to try and repeal and replace Obamacare countless times, and the very thing that the Roberts court in fact determined was a tax.
Now, importantly, Butler was trying to solve this not to expand coverage or improve outcomes, but ultimately to contain costs. He was attempting to devise a way to tax citizens and provide them with direct funds to manage their own healthcare needs. Very much akin to Uncle Nippledick’s (Milton Friedman, of course) idea of catastrophic insurance for all with individual spending accounts. Whereas Democrats ultimately embraced the plan, along with every other for-profit provider in the country, the original conservatives were trying to dismantle the entire system, especially entitlements like Medicare and Medicaid. Same inputs. Vastly different desired outputs.
All the seats at the table
It would have been impossible to do this series without a book I mentioned last time that an Unf*cker recommended titled The Social Transformation of American Medicine, by Paul Starr. At the very least, this would have been different. I want to share a passage that perfectly illustrates the tension that we discussed last piece because it will help us set the table for the two main areas that we’re going to focus on today, and that’s insurance companies and hospitals. Here’s Starr:
“The dynamics of the system in everyday life are simple to follow. Patients want the best medical services available. Providers know that the more services they give and the more complex the services are, the more they earn and the more they are likely to please their clients. Besides, physicians are trained to practice medicine at the highest level of technical quality without regard to cost. Hospitals want to retain their patients, physicians and community support by offering the maximum range of services and the most modern technology, often regardless of whether they are duplicating services offered by other institutions nearby. Though insurance companies would prefer to avoid the uncertainty that rising prices create, they have generally been able to pass along the costs to their subscribers, and their profits increase with the total volume of expenditures. No one in the system stands to lose from its expansion.”
This last point, the idea that everyone in the system stands to gain from expansion, is tantamount to understanding how our system developed over time and why the ACA codified, and in many ways bolstered, the standing of profit oriented organizations. As far as the “who” that Starr refers to, the “no ones in the system,” we gave a partial list last time, but let’s zoom out a bit to really drive this point home.
Again, not a complete list, but a much more comprehensive view of stakeholders in the system derived from a list of SIC codes, or the Standard Industrial Classification system in America. These are the ones who benefit from expansion, and they all had a seat at the table in designing the system even further under the Affordable Care Act.
-
Skilled nursing facilities
-
Assisted living facilities
-
Home healthcare
-
Chronic disease specialists
-
Medical research
-
Medical schools
-
Health care apparel and supplies
-
Inpatient and outpatient rehabilitation services
-
Laboratories
-
Obstetrics, osteopathy, oncology, ophthalmology
-
Pediatrics to podiatry
-
Medical malpractice attorneys
-
Dentists
-
Dental supply companies
-
Abortion providers
-
The Catholic Church
-
Oxygen providers
-
Insurance brokers
-
Tribal health services
-
Blood banks
-
Sperm banks
-
Prosthetics
-
Wheelchairs and accessibility devices
-
Hearing aids and eyeglasses
-
Plastic surgery, cosmetic surgery
-
Hyperbaric oxygen chambers
-
End of life care
-
Electronic medical record companies
-
Billing companies
-
Mental health care providers from psychologists to psychiatrists
-
Chiropractic care
-
Naturopaths
-
Physical therapists
-
Medical device manufacturers
-
General practitioners
-
Hospitals
-
Insurers
-
Collection companies
-
Pharmaceutical companies
-
Pharmacy benefit managers
-
Pharmacies
-
Independent pharmacies
-
Emergency care providers like EMTs and ambulance drivers
-
Anesthesiologists
-
Medical contracting and construction firms
-
Labor unions
That doesn’t include agencies like the VA or the myriad regulatory bodies that oversee each level of care. Or the FDA. USDA. Social Services. Medicare. Medicaid, etc. These are just the organizations largely incentivized by profit. The ones who only stand to gain from expansion. And every single one of them had a seat at the table when designing the system.
Chapter Two
The Insurance Class System
Insurance exists in other countries. Canada has private insurance you can buy to layer on coverage. China, as I mentioned before, has an insurance industry. Germany has private insurance to fill in gaps. But the most common thread among these other nations is that the baseline insurance is federal. Government insurance subsidized through taxation that automatically enrolls every citizen to cover preventive and routine care, emergency medical procedures and even long-term and chronic care.
In most other countries, private insurance can potentially cover elective procedures or low coverage areas like vision and dental. Employers and employees pay into the systems through deductions and the government supplements funding by taxing certain industries like alcohol and pharmaceuticals. Costs are primarily contained by the government setting the price of procedures, visits, prescriptions and the like. If you need a solid example to wrap your head around how it works, here’s one:
Medicare.
This is essentially how Medicare works, although the government has slightly less control over the cost of certain items like pharmaceuticals. That’s why it was such an important move to include negotiating power for prescription drugs and a cap on out-of-pocket expenses to seniors in the Inflation Reduction Act.
But, to keep things really simple, when we talk about universal healthcare in this country, it is not always the same thing as Medicare for All. I know that sounds obvious, but it’s a really important point.
Universal healthcare is what the ACA was driving at through a complex network of coverage schemes cobbled together to provide varying levels of coverage that differ from state to state. Medicaid for low income individuals and families. Medicare and its different parts for seniors. Employer based insurance. Exchanges for seasonal workers, gig workers, part-timers, freelancers or the unemployed to purchase healthcare. Special considerations for veterans. Tribal health services. Social services and nonprofits that receive federal aid and stand in for government programs, especially in areas concerning mental health.
All of which leaves the citizens of the United States in a rather precarious position. Depending upon your level of employment, station in life, age or occupation, it’s all different.
The insurance coverage scheme has created a class system in America. To address this, we have to talk about the Affordable Care Act.
While the ACA brought millions of Americans into coverage, gaps remain. As of right now, however, the percentage of uninsured Americans dropped from persistent double digits to around 9%. Not bad. Except that the number of underinsured is still much higher. And that 9% equates to 26 million people. (That’s the size of Australia’s population.)
Medicare is treated like a trophy in this country. Something you get for crossing the finish line of 65. And maybe that was a little more appealing before our fucking mortality rates started rising. (For a little context, countries like Japan didn’t see a rise in mortality during COVID, and every comparable nation recovered after initial drops. But not us.) So now we’re in a situation where we’re dying younger and finding it harder to afford quality care.
Another unique feature in the United States is the phenomenon of bankruptcies due to medical costs. A Kaiser Family Foundation report, in collaboration with The New York Times, conducted a qualitative analysis of medical debt and found that many who struggle with medical debt and file for bankruptcy had insurance. But the costs beyond their coverage placed them into debt.
Dead Kennedy and Dennis Kucinich
Despite attempts as early as the Bull Moose Party under Teddy Roosevelt and several administrations from FDR and Truman, Kennedy and even Nixon, the pursuit of a universal system of healthcare coverage has eluded the political class. Despite the overwhelming popularity for some form of universal coverage from a public option to Medicare for All, the political class has been unable to muster the momentum to pursue it.
First off, as we’ll examine below, there are practical reasons why a public option within the current structure isn’t really viable. And, to be clear, there are more in favor of this route than a Medicare for All. To understand the distinction between them, it’s instructive to look at the circuitous path the ACA took to becoming settled law in the United States. It’s ugly. And fascinating. And frustrating.
Hillary Clinton, Joe Biden, Chris Dodd, John Edwards, Barack Obama and others were vying for the Democratic nomination in 2008. The real race was between Clinton, Obama and Edwards from the beginning, with most candidates withdrawing in January, including Edwards, and former Alaska Senator Mike Gravel pulling out in March. Only one candidate among all the Democrats running that year publicly endorsed Medicare for All. Dennis Kucinich.
But healthcare was a hot topic, and no one was more prepared than Hillary Clinton, who had the most time in the game from attempting to devise a universal coverage plan during her husband’s tenure in office.
The only candidate who didn’t have a plan, like at all, was (ironically) Barack Obama.
This is where Steven Brill’s detailed account of the ACA in his book America’s Bitter Pill really shines. He recounts the 2007 primary debate in Las Vegas where the candidates were pressed on healthcare, saying:
“The other candidates were crisp, knowledgeable, and specific, especially John Edwards, who freely acknowledged that he would end the Bush-era tax cuts for both the middle and upper classes in order to pay for expanded healthcare. And then there was Hillary Clinton. The New York senator stole the show. Her standing, strolling presentation was a tour de force of personal stories, sophisticated detail, easily understandable data, and great one-liners… Barack Obama, the former Harvard Law Review president and boy wonder senator, was not used to not being the smartest guy in the room.”
From this point forward, Obama would commit himself fully to understanding the magnitude of the healthcare problem and committing to many of the policies enumerated by his competitors, much to their great annoyance.
And yet, upon taking office, something remarkable happened. Full acquiescence. Once officially the POTUS, Obama had a stimulus package to work through Congress to save the imploding American economy. For better or worse, Congress was shockingly prepared to take the ball and run with it and the new president was all too happy to let this happen.
Brill provides a brilliant, almost minute-to-minute breakdown of what happened from this point to the passage of the ACA, the bill then Vice President Biden called a “big fucking deal” on a hot mic. (Actually, it wasn’t even a hot mic. My man was still at the fucking podium and said it with an Irish whisper to Obama.)
Anyway, while Obama was busy plugging holes in the economy, a few stars were aligning in the Democratic Party. First off, Ted Kennedy was dying. That sounded terrible, sorry. But this, too, was a big fucking deal because he was determined to make expanding healthcare his legacy.
Another senator, Max Baucus from Montana, was also interested in solidifying his legacy as a reformer after a lackluster career as a conservative Democrat. Baucus was critical, as he was the chair of the powerful finance committee.
The big question on everyone’s mind was whether or not any reform would be filibuster proof. In the end, this technicality didn’t matter, and we won’t get into the specifics of it today. But it was important at the outset because the Democrats came into office with 58 senators. Two away from being filibuster proof. Then, a miracle happened. Arlen Specter switched parties and Al Franken was finally elected after a contested recount. With Bernie, that made 60.
But first, the Democrats had to develop a plan. And then, herd the cats.
Chapter Three
Making the Sausage
As we dig into the considerations during deliberation over the ACA, just a couple of quick definitions.
MLR, or Medical Loss Ratio
This is essentially a way to cap insurance company profits. As Steven Brill notes, “The MLR is the ratio of claims insurers pay out to hospitals, doctors and other providers of medical care compared to the premiums they receive from customers who buy their insurance.”
On Wall Street, a low MLR was considered a badge of honor. A reason for investing in insurance companies. One of the most outspoken members of the newly formed administration was shit head Larry Summers, who worked behind the scenes to eliminate any talk of capping profits because, well, he’s a fucking asshole.
Age Band
This is an equation that determines how much older people could be charged relative to younger insured members.
Another important distinction in America. In most other countries, coverage is coverage. Even though it certainly costs more to care for seniors, most nations use the law of large numbers to spread the costs among the healthy population.
Federal Mandate
Ah, yes. The requirement to have coverage. This became the fulcrum of the debate. Forcing Americans to do anything doesn’t exactly land well in the court of public opinion. The idea here is to compel people to carry coverage or to tax them, which is ultimately what we wound up with. But in the beginning, it was absent from any White House talking points. And it was this element of the ACA that had its roots in the Heritage Foundation plan to essentially punish so-called freeloaders in the system.
Of course, this would inspire two things: 1) Upholding the ACA in court battles because it was considered a tax. And, 2) it would become a rallying cry for the burgeoning Tea Party and all subsequent opposition to Obamacare.
Adverse selection
The reason for the mandate is something economists refer to as “adverse selection.” Essentially, young, healthy people don’t feel the need to sign up for health insurance, and those are exactly the type of people that a plan needs to limit exposure and build numbers. Otherwise, exchanges would be filled with seniors and sick people.
This is how other countries are able to avoid things like the Age Band. And how they’re able to contain costs and negotiate rates. With everyone in the system, there’s enough money to go around to fund care and offer coverage. Everyone at the table understood that any plan would have to include millions of new “customers” in order to make the numbers work.
Public Option
This is a tricky one because it’s often confused with Medicare for All. Instead of the government taking over healthcare, it would provide a consumer option for a government run insurance plan.
The reason this never got off the ground is because it’s impossible to square with the private insurance industry. The only reason you would provide a public option is to allow people to buy into a system that purchases healthcare services at the same rate the government, basically Medicare, already enjoys. This would make private insurers completely uncompetitive. So fucking what, right?
So fucking this: Everyone from Baucus to Obama left it off the table in the initial negotiations because they knew too many of their colleagues who were in the pockets of insurers would balk at the plan. In the end, it was actually Connecticut Senator Joe Lieberman who killed it once and for all when advocates insisted on including it. As Brill writes:
“The Connecticut senator finally got rid of the public option, including a version that allowed individual states to choose to implement it or not. Lieberman also shot down an alternative that would have allowed people 55 years old or older to buy into Medicare so they could be protected, but pay lower premiums from 2010 until 2014, when the exchanges, with their premium subsidies, would kick in.”
With some definitions and understanding of the scope, let’s recap a little.
At this crucial point in history when Democrats had 60 votes in the Senate, control of the House and a president who was embarrassed enough by Hillary Clinton and John Edwards to make universal coverage a lynchpin in his agenda, the stars were more aligned than they had been for decades. From the start, however, save for Bernie yelling from the wings and Dennis Kucinich proposing it from the fringe, no one was talking seriously about Medicare for All.
The only question now was how the Democrats would wrangle compromise from within its own party. And the person in charge immediately threw it to the herd to figure out. That meant the Senate primarily, with all of the special interest groups and state level interests, would be coming up with the plan alone. Even Nancy Pelosi and House Democrats were essentially shut out of the process. Time was of the essence, and the Senate began closing ranks. And the litany of self inflicted wounds was only just beginning.
Of course, there were external factors at play.
There is a now infamous story of a dinner where pollster Frank Luntz, Newt Gingrich, Mitch McConnell, Eric Cantor, Paul Ryan and Bob Corker, among others, gathered to devise a strategy to kill Obamacare right out of the gate, an insurance plan literally modeled on Romneycare, which was crafted and conceived by their beloved Heritage Foundation. Luntz and Gingrich were there because they were the authors of Newt’s successful Contract with America, the ten point plan devised to derail the Clinton presidency. They were experts at tanking public agendas.
They devised a public relations strategy, with now familiar talking points and framing, that would sit sideways in the ass of the American public. Phrases like “government takeover.” “Protecting the sacred doctor-patient relationship.” “Death tax and death panels.” And the ever popular “socialized medicine.”
“Keep government out of my healthcare” became a familiar Tea Party rallying cry happily stoked by Luntz and crew. And it was working. Every rally, every town hall that was interrupted, every angry Fox News commentator that hammered away at these points made a dent in the public psyche. And the longer the negotiations went on in the Democratic caucus, the more fearful the members became.
Senate Democrats, meanwhile, had a host of considerations on the table, each with a special interest group attached. Some would make it into the final bill. Many would be killed by said special interest groups.
Options like providing Americans the ability to purchase prescription drugs from Canada.
Nope.
Giving Medicare the ability to negotiate drug prices.
Nuh-uh.
The public option.
Sorry, Charlie.
Tort Reform.
Try again.
Cadillac tax on expensive plans subsidized by corporations?
A medical device tax?
Insurance company profit tax?
No, no and…no. But thanks for playing!
There were other considerations, like patent protection on certain drugs and therapies. What role the states would play in rolling out exchanges or providing their own plans. Whether abortion or contraception would be covered on plans sold through the exchanges. What was to be done about the Age Band, medical loss ratio and what would the character of the federal mandate be?
There was also the question of getting this thing paid for. Almost every candidate, and certainly the Obama White House, had run on the theory that expanding coverage through insurance exchanges would be budget neutral and eventually save the country money because so many new customers would be competing for healthcare, the market would respond by cutting costs in a more competitive environment.
How’s that working out?
There was also the question of subsidies. Setting up public exchanges didn’t mean that everyone could afford to buy into it. So they had to agree on a formula. Whether it would kick in for incomes 300% or 400% above the poverty line became a huge sticking point. And it made a huge difference in the high cost of living areas. Senate Democrats knew from the modeling that setting the limit at 300% above the line would still prevent millions from qualifying for subsidies. So, initially, they set it at 400%.
Then there was the political reality of getting it through Congress. For most of the negotiations, Senate Democrats operated under the assumption that they required all 60 votes to pass a comprehensive bill. In reality, this didn’t turn out to be the case because the ACA was ultimately considered a reconciliation bill and it didn’t require the 60 vote, filibuster proof threshold. This single point of view, taken as gospel from the beginning, meant that all of the special interests were able to negotiate favorable carve outs. And, by the time it was understood that 60 votes weren’t needed, the plan was so far along in the process that it was unfathomable to start over.
On top of this, there was bad news coming and challenges out of left field the team faced. As Brill writes:
“On July 17 [2009], the Congressional Budget Office announced what one of Obama’s healthcare aides called ‘a bombshell’... The CBO had just scored the House bill and declared that it would not result in any significant long-term healthcare savings.”
This was a disaster for Democrats, who were stunned by the CBO findings. Those intimately involved in the process went from using scalpels to hatchets to work the CBO estimates down to something resembling cost neutral. The longer the process went on, considering the economy was still in free fall, the less tolerance politicians had for spending. They were already about to propose a nearly $800 billion bailout plan. Anything more seemed like a bridge too far.
To complicate matters further, Obama had an unfortunate exchange at Ted Kennedy’s funeral, of all places. Again, Brill:
“One of the Catholic bishops in attendance bent his ear about abortion: The president risked the opposition of the church (and, by inference, legislators, particularly conservative Democrats in the House) if he didn’t make sure that no one got subsidized premiums to buy insurance that included coverage for abortions. There was even, he was told, strong opposition to insurance that paid for birth control.”
And we can’t forget about the Republicans. As a semblance of a bill began to take shape, Mitch McConnell introduced a poison pill by signaling their support for an amendment sponsored by liberal Democrats that would allow consumers to buy drugs from Canada. Fucking devious and brilliant. As Brill notes:
“On the merits, most Democrats loved importation. It would save consumers—and cost the drug companies—$400 billion over the next ten years… [Harry] Reid spared the dilemma of voting against something they favored. He refused to let it come up for a vote at all.”
In the end, the Senate would deliver a massive spending bill to the House with so many twists, turns, caveats and carve outs that Nancy Pelosi didn’t know what to do. She had been perturbed all along that the Senate was running roughshod over the House, but by the time the bill was sent, she had little choice but to corral her members and sign on, even admitting to the media that it was too long to read but that they would work out any details when the bills were paired. If you don’t recall this brouhaha, you can imagine how that went over in the conservative press.
Profits, profits everywhere.
Almost everyone in for-profit care got what they wanted. All except the doctors and the patients. In our final installment next week, we’re going to talk about hospital systems and comparative outcomes, but I want to finish with a few thoughts about insurance companies and the Frankenbill that is the ACA.
The reason a for-profit insurance based system is fucked from jump street is because of misaligned incentives. All the caps we talked about related to MLRs or Age Bands, or taxes on Cadillac plans and equipment, mostly went out the window in return for support from insurance companies.
To be clear, they did agree to a couple of important things. The insurance companies would have to pony up billions of dollars to compensate for the flood of new customers. Hospitals and pharma companies would as well. But, as many observers on Wall Street keenly noted at the time, no matter the size of these givebacks, the amount of new customers into the system was going to be a massive win for all the for-profit companies, bar none.
Eventually, the bill took so long to negotiate, the Democrats actually lost their majority when Ted Kennedy passed away and Scott Brown upset the apple cart to win the open seat, campaigning primarily against the pending federal mandate. This would prove to be a useful blueprint for Republicans in the midterms.
In fact, so many crucial financing portions of the bill had been cut by special interest groups along the way that legislators quietly changed the poverty subsidy threshold from 400% to 300% to protect the neutral CBO score.
Womp. Womp.
While there were a lot of winners in private industries, there’s no question that the insurance companies made out the best. All along, they had the most to lose, and they knew it. It’s why they were so early at the bargaining table and so willing to ultimately fork over $102 billion over ten years to help fund implementation of the ACA.
An insurance company isn’t incentivized to pay for patient care. As a for-profit entity, it has two incentives. Enroll as many people as it can at the highest cost possible and pay as little as possible for their care. It all goes back to this. Costs are almost meaningless. It’s what the so-called market, or several markets actually, will bear and who has the most leverage within the system.
For example, the entire underpinning of medical billing is an elaborate system of billing codes. Prescribe a drug. Take a urine sample. Order an MRI. Give out an aspirin. Take blood pressure. Perform open heart surgery. Do a hip replacement. Everything has a code, and that code has a cost. Except it’s not the cost. It’s a starting point. Like an MSRP for a new car. In a hospital, they call it a chargemaster, which has been a huge source of controversy ever since Steven Brill began writing a series of New Yorker articles before he published America’s Bitter Pill.
So your doctor—or the team in charge of your care in the hospital—will tally up every little thing that happens from room and board for pre and post-op recovery days to the nurse that takes your vitals. Then the negotiation begins. In a hospital setting, or in a large physician practice group or specialty group, there are tiers of strength. Big New York, New England, Chicago and California hospital systems get paid a lot closer to enumerated costs on the chargemaster than a small non-profit hospital in the midwest.
A physician specialty practice group has more power than an independent doctor. A group of doctors can command more than a sole practitioner, and so on.
Though, on the general practitioner side of things, even the groups are finding it nearly impossible to compete, which is why so many practice groups are being swallowed up by hospital systems. And when hospitals themselves consolidate, it usually means a reduction in the amount of beds. In fact, the number of hospital beds has declined precipitously in recent years. A reality that came back to bite us in the ass when COVID filled beds all throughout the country. But beds distributed throughout a region are difficult to manage. And expensive. So, if you can consolidate the big stuff under one roof on a primary campus and convert outlier hospitals to glorified emergency rooms that can transport serious care needs by ambulance or helicopter, it’s a lot more cost effective for the hospital.
And that’s the name of the game. Get big to get small. And charge the fuck out of the patient for everything under the sun.
We’re going to dive deep into the hospital systems in the next episode, but this gives a sense of where the problem really begins. With insurance and reimbursements.
Recall from our primer essay that profits in the insurance industry are extremely healthy. We gave examples of three of the big ones out of the nearly 1,000 registered providers in the country:
-
UnitedHealth Group posted $17 billion in profit for 2021.
-
Humana posted $3 billion.
-
And Anthem posted $6 billion.
All told, revenues for the health insurance industry topped $1.2 trillion dollars in 2021. (Those are yours and my premiums.) What’s important to recognize is that the profit margins aren’t exorbitant. In fact, margins overall range from 1.5% to 4% over a multi-year period. That’s not the issue. The issue is that they’re guaranteed.
They can’t lose because they set the rates, and the hospitals and physicians are incentivized to keep charging higher and higher costs to fuel their growth. It’s a vicious cycle that will be unstoppable, barring extreme intervention into the perverse market based system that only the United States operates under.
So, the final installment of the series will look at the cost drivers in hospitals themselves, along with some caveats for Big Pharma. While profits are greater in pharma as a percentage of revenue, the revenue picture is half that of the insurance industry, for some perspective. Overall, Big Pharma accounts for only 10% of total healthcare spending in the United States. So, we’re going to save the pharma analysis for another time when we unf*ck PBMs, patent protection issues and pricing of key drugs that strain a significant portion of the population.
For now, we’re going to stay focused on the two biggest drivers of cost—insurance and hospitals—because they feed off one another in a self perpetuating cycle of madness that will know no boundaries unless, and until, we someday get serious about Medicare for All. And, in the conclusion of the series next week, we’ll talk about a handful of necessary but Sisyphean steps that must be taken to get there.
The ACA wasn’t a bridge. It was a wall.
There’s no profit in a healthy population.
COVID should have been the catalyst.
Here endeth Part Two.
Bonus script from the audio version of this essay.
If UNFTR was a Big Pharma ad:
It’s the dawn of a bright new day in healthcare. Millions of Americans are rediscovering hope with a weekly dose of UNFTR.
Patient Testimonial 1: “After January 6th, I had trouble sleeping and focusing during the day. Then I started listening to UNFTR. And now I’m just fucking pissed off. All the time.”
Patient Testimonial 2: “For years, I thought I was losing my mind. Then I realized that it was the rest of the country that had lost its mind. Thanks UNFTR!
UNFTR reduces the pressure on the cerebral cortex, the part of the brain responsible for reason, language and learning. By exposing your mind to consistent bombs of truth, UNFTR works to reduce those “why is this happening?” moments and allows you to see clearly what’s really going on in the world.
IMPORTANT DISCLAIMER: The clinical name for UNFTR is Unf*cking the Republic. Do not take UNFTR if you have a history of listening to conservative talk radio or alt right programming including Rush Limbaugh, Dennis Prager, Ben Shapiro, Michael Knowles, Candace Owens, Sean Hannity, Laura Ingraham, Tucker Carlson, Glenn Beck, Mark Levin, Dave Ramsey, Michael Savage, Charlie Kirk, Bill O’Reilly, John Stossel, Bret Baier and Sean Spicer. Mixing UNFTR with right wing propaganda may cause severe side effects like spontaneous combustion or explosive diarrhea. Studies have shown that consuming UNFTR over a long period of time may also result in an irrational hatred for Chicago School economists. Avoid UNFTR if you’re allergic to profanity or facts. Serious side effects may include screaming at your relatives over holiday meals, unfriending most of your high school friends on social media platforms and profound feelings of isolation and rage.
To help see the world clearly and meet people where they are, I take UNFTR. Ask your doctor if listening to UNFTR is right for you.

Part Three: Hospitals and Healthcare: From Sanatoriums for the Indigent to Citadels of the Elite.
Summary: The third and final installment of our American Healthcare series examines the evolution of the American hospital system. There are more than 6,000 hospitals in the United States and several distinctions among them. After a quick recap of the first two parts, we look primarily at the peculiar designation of nonprofit hospitals, their relationship to practitioners and their role in driving costs in the system. We conclude the series with a few hot takes from medical professionals, some basic proposals to improve coverage and care and ask what it would take to move toward Medicare for All.
Welcome back to this final installment of the ‘not series’ that turned into a three part series where we look at the hospital system specifically. The usual slew of caveats apply here as well.
First, this won’t be exhaustive. It will be a streamlined overview of the primary systems the majority of us encounter and the areas of the industry that drive revenue and costs. So, we won’t be looking at systems like the VA, urgent care centers or tribal health centers, to name a few.
Also, it should go without saying that hospitals are complex institutions. They bring the majority of us into the world today. They typically play a role on the way out. The providers perform miracles on an almost daily basis, many of which were inconceivable within our lifetimes. And sometimes they don’t. Naturally, the subject of hospitals is highly charged.
So let me state up front that I believe in the people within these systems. We may not be hanging out of our windows banging pots in celebration of healthcare professionals every evening, but we should.
Now, because this is a series and we’ve covered a lot of ground thus far, I think it’s helpful to recap a bit. One of the things I’ve been trying to focus on lately is to emphasize key takeaways and talking points, especially in the “Bring it Home, Max” sections. Sometimes, we cover so much ground that the important nuggets and facts that would be useful in conversation later get lost in the shuffle. So I’m making a deliberate effort to reinforce important points to help us all develop a shared language and understanding.
With that, here are the key takeaways from Part One:
-
Fringe Benefit. The American concept of health coverage, which is distinct from care but is essential to understanding access, was formulated as a “fringe benefit” rather than a natural right. Just the nomenclature alone gives us insight into how the system has evolved.
-
The Inflation Reduction Act. The act contains key provisions that alleviate the financial burden on seniors where prescription drugs are concerned, including Medicare having the ability to negotiate drug prices for specific drugs and a cap on out of pocket expenses for seniors. In a couple of years. Which is stupid. But at least it’s coming.
-
Healthcare Economy. Healthcare spending represents 20% of the nation’s GDP. An astonishing number that illustrates the sheer size of the industry, and therefore the challenge we face in reforming it.
-
Universal Opposition. Prior to the New Deal, there were attempts to pursue a universal system of coverage, but this progressive concept took a backseat during World War II, and subsequently, due to a number of factors. For one, there was a growing stigma attached to all things socialized. The largest opposition at the time came from the AMA, as physicians were concerned that a government run system of healthcare would negatively impact their ability to practice medicine freely. Labor unions also balked at a universal system because it would have eliminated one of their key competitive advantages and benefits. And new technologies were developing rapidly in collaboration with the private sector.
-
Europe v. The United States. The developing European model centered around the patient. The burgeoning American model centered around payments. Both theoretically contemplated access to care, but the very nature of the approach meant that, as the industry grew, the incentives grew further and further apart.
-
Employer Based Insurance. One of the ways in which the United States nurtured the payment based model was the structural incentives that favored employer based insurance. Both employee and employer contributions to coverage for care became tax exempt in 1954, which spurred investment into insurance products, and we haven’t looked back since. This resulted in a regressive system that pitted the ‘haves versus the have nots’ in medical care and left millions of Americans uninsured or underinsured at the precise moment that advancements in medicine were booming and spending was increasing and driving the cost of care.
-
Perverse Incentives. The system that evolved over the years contributed to the widening gap in healthcare outcomes along ethnic, racial and socioeconomic lines. The more advanced the solutions, the greater the cost. The greater the cost, the greater the pushback against reimbursements. The higher the premiums, the more tenuous the coverage. And so on and so on. And because nearly every stakeholder in the American system is ultimately incentivized by profits, the greater the push to increase costs, increase premiums and deny coverage. It’s a self-fulfilling cycle of profiteering designed to protect profits over patients.
Remember, there are 2,000 pharmaceutical companies, 6,000 hospitals, 6,500 device manufacturers and 1,000 insurance companies all vying for your healthcare dollars. The example we gave was that 12 of the bigger companies out of these more than 15,000 private companies posted $99 billion in profits in 2021 alone. 12 out of 15,000.
Your sickness is big business. And, because we have a system built around a for-profit network of companies, it means that shareholders are the ultimate beneficiaries of your illness. Furthermore, we returned to another important talking point that is largely lost in the discussion, and that is who these shareholders are. 90% of equities in this country are owned by 10% of the population. So, just a little extrapolation, and it’s clear who the system is designed to benefit.
Key takeaways from Part Two:
-
The Insurance Industry. In Part Two, we looked more closely at the insurance industry. While we listed the endless number of sectors within healthcare drawn from the list of Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes, we wanted to hone in on the insurance industry as the known villain and major cost driver. Not because they necessarily take more profit off the table, but because they have negotiated a position where they can guarantee their profits. A key distinction.
-
Mortality Rates. As we drilled deeper into the insurance cabal, we highlighted a couple key metrics to demonstrate the madness of a profit based system with for-profit third party insurers determining not only the cost of provided care, but what can and will be covered. We put this against the backdrop of the greatest increase in U.S. mortality rates since the mid 1920s. All while spending double that of most other developed nations per capita.
-
Federal Mandate. One of the most important elements of the Affordable Care Act (ACA), known as Obamacare, was the inclusion of a federal mandate. Essentially, this is the requirement that everyone has coverage. If you don’t qualify for employer based insurance or government programs such as Medicaid, Medicare or VA coverage, you are required to sign up for insurance on the newly formed exchanges. If you fall within a certain income threshold, you might qualify for federal subsidies. If you are financially able to acquire coverage and choose not to, you’ll be subject to a fine.
-
Adverse Selection. The reason for this last provision relates to a concept economists call adverse selection. The theory is that young, healthy people have little incentive to go out of pocket for insurance, so the federal mandate instituted a penalty for opting out. Insurance requires numbers to spread the risk and make financial sense. Republicans were able to successfully counter this provision in the court of public opinion by positioning the mandate as an attack on personal freedoms and liberty.
-
The Heritage Plan. Thankfully, this was the only court in which the Democrats lost the battle. Because, in the court that really matters, the Roberts Supreme Court, legal challenges to the ACA were shot down because the federal mandate was treated as a tax. This turned a generation of conservative voters indoctrinated by Fox News into Roberts detractors, but it saved the ACA. Of course, we also reviewed the fact that the federal mandate was actually a Heritage Foundation invention that became the model for Romneycare in Massachusetts. The original intent behind the federal mandate was to punish so-called freeloaders in the system that utilized emergency room care as primary care.
-
Making the Sausage. The balance of Part Two peeked under the hood of the legislative process to pass the ACA, and how the settled law actually took us further away from the dream of Medicare for All. Even though the intent of the legislation was to develop an insurance-based system that provided universal coverage and contain costs by adding millions of healthy people into the system, the dream was never fully realized.
-
Bankrupt. That’s not to say there weren’t positive aspects in terms of coverage. Millions of Americans did take advantage of the public exchanges, and the number of uninsured Americans, and children in particular, dropped precipitously and continues to do so. And, of course, America still has the unique distinction of having a million Americans file for bankruptcy each year due to medical costs. And that includes a significant percentage of the insured population.
-
26 Million Uninsured. In fact, only 9% of the nation is currently uninsured, which is historic. Unfortunately, 9% of the population equates to 26 million people, which as we noted, is the size of Australia’s population.
-
Spiraling Costs. Even more troubling to ACA advocates is the fact that costs weren’t contained by any demonstrable means. In fact, healthcare costs continue to spiral out of control, despite attempts by the Biden administration to curtail spending on prescription drugs in the Inflation Reduction Act.
-
Thresholds. We rounded out Part Two with a discussion surrounding a couple of important thresholds. The first is the 60 vote filibuster-proof threshold in the Senate. From the outset of the drive to Obamacare, the Senate operated under the assumption that the ACA would be a pure legislative act and not necessarily a spending bill. This distinction led all those involved to believe that all 60 votes in the Senate, which included Bernie Sanders as an independent, the newly elected Al Franken and Arlen Specter who switched parties. What makes this so critical to understand is that every Senator at the table was essential. A single defection meant it was over. And behind every Senator involved was a special interest group, donor or even personal issue that showed up in the text. Common sense provisions that would have brought millions more under coverage, potentially reduced costs to consumers and tightened controls over special interests all got watered down in the final bill.
The other threshold was determining who would qualify for a subsidy on the open exchanges. It was originally set at 400% above the poverty threshold, which brought a few million people into the fold. But when The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) scored the entire package slightly less than neutral, meaning the ACA wouldn’t deliver cost savings over a ten year period, Democrats freaked the fuck out. One of the easiest pickups was to change the poverty threshold calculation from 400% to 300%, which cast aside millions of middle class income earners.
In the end, the ACA was passed as an omnibus spending bill, which meant that it only required a simple majority. So a handful of conservative Democrats wound up voting against it to maintain their conservative bonafides ahead of the midterm elections and the bill passed anyway, which meant all the giveaways to these fuckers didn’t matter in the long run.
Now you know. And knowing is half the battle. -G.I. Joe
Chapter One
What’s a Hospital?
It’s a big building with patients in it, but that’s not important right now.
(Inserts laugh track)
Hospitals come in several shapes and forms and these forms vary throughout the world. Colombia, for example, boasts more than 10,000 hospitals, compared to 6,000 in the United States. For reference, Japan has more than 8,000, France has 3,000, Canada has 700, New Zealand, 150. Location, services, number of beds, population density and other factors contribute to the total number.
The numbers can fluctuate depending upon the data sources and technical considerations. Inpatient versus outpatient or ambulatory care, emergency or urgent care services, addiction recovery, specialty practices with surgical capabilities and recovery units. I offer these distinctions because the United States tends to have far superior levels of specialty care in outpatient settings that might otherwise be tended to in a hospital setting elsewhere.
Where the U.S. is concerned, there are major differences among and between institutions considered part of the 6,000, which is our focus today. The vast majority of hospitals in the United States are acute-care facilities, meaning they specialize in short-term care for certain diseases, surgeries, emergency services and the like. Long-term care facilities are usually reserved for chronic treatments like rehabilitation or psychiatric services. I mentioned in one of the prior episodes that we’re going to carve out psychiatric care from these episodes because that journey is distinct in America and there are more political and sociological factors at play.
Further distinctions include federal and state run hospitals. The most visible within this category is probably the Veterans Administration (VA). And There are a handful of state and local run hospitals and clinics, but these are few and far between.
Now here’s where it gets a little dense.
Technically, any hospital that isn’t run by local, state or federal government is considered a “community hospital.” But that term carries some baggage because it seems almost too parochial. A large for-profit hospital within a larger system would technically be considered a community hospital because it exists to serve the surrounding community. But we are more likely to associate a community hospital with a physician-run rural facility.
There are a couple more examples, like teaching versus non-teaching, which just means there’s a medical school attached to it or not. Then there’s the difference between a network and a system. Here’s a quick breakdown from the American Hospital Association:
“A system is defined as either a multihospital or a diversified single hospital system. A multihospital system is two or more hospitals owned, leased, sponsored or contract managed by a central organization. Single, freestanding hospitals may be categorized as a system by bringing into membership three or more, and at least 25 percent, of their owned or leased non-hospital pre-acute or post-acute health care organizations. System affiliation does not preclude network participation.”
So, for reference, all together these distinct organizations comprise the 6,000 or so hospitals. We won’t be covering the federal or psychiatric care facilities, nor will we parse the nuance of networks and systems or high growth areas of independent urgent care and outpatient facilities. What we will be talking about is the difference between for-profit and nonprofit hospitals. Despite the implication of the nonprofit name, believe me, it’s all about the bottom line.
Chapter Two
For-Profit and Nonprofit Hospitals. Two sides of the same damn coin.
“In developing from places of dreaded impurity and exiled human wreckage into awesome citadels of science and bureaucratic order, they acquired a new moral identity, as well as new purposes and patients of higher status. The hospital is perhaps distinctive among social organizations in having first been built primarily for the poor and only later entered in significant numbers and an entirely different state of mind by the more respectable classes.”
That’s a passage from The Social Transformation of American Medicine. What it conveys is the remarkable evolution of the hospital from social dumping ground to elite ivory towers of medicine. For most of history, if you were ill, the hospital was the last place you wanted to end up. It’s another important reminder as we continue that the field of medicine—the advancements in diagnostics and treatments—is nothing short of miraculous. The sheer amount of knowledge accumulated since World War II is unprecedented in human history.
And perhaps that makes this series, and all things healthcare in this country, even more frustrating. These achievements should be glorified and lauded. Shared and available. Accessible and affordable. Instead, the very best of it remains out of reach for the vast majority of the public. Here. In America.
When we talk about villains, we usually think about insurance companies and Big Pharma. We’ve done enough unpacking of insurance to concur with this assessment.
But remember that Big Pharma, as fucked up as it is, accounts for only 10% of the healthcare spending. Of course, that’s still big, and the revenue and profit picture is tremendous. But hospitals account for 30% and over the past two decades, their costs—or should I say revenue—has increased dramatically. And why not? The bigger they are, the more leverage they have on payments. They also have a new pool of paying customers through Obamacare that might have previously sought free emergency care. That increased revenue stream incentivized massive consolidation, as there are no laws on the books to restrain hospital system growth or to prevent near monopolies in geographic regions.
One caveat to this. Curiously, there are laws in certain states that prohibit hospital expansion; presumably to prevent hospitals from crowding out ancillary services and providers. And this used to be a much bigger deal. But hospitals have skirted most of these rules by pursuing mergers and consolidating either in a network or a system as we discussed. And mergers like this aren’t cheap. They might achieve efficiencies over time, but in the initial stages, mergers and acquisitions are expensive endeavors.
Another distinction is the physician-owned hospital. These are pretty rare and interesting, as there are only about 240 of them left in the U.S. The government makes these facilities jump through hoops when it comes to expansion because there is a belief that physicians have an embedded conflict of interest. Therefore, they are required to seek an exemption should they want to expand. I bring this up because I find it fascinating that regulators believe physicians have a greater conflict than nearly every other provider, supplier, insurer and manufacturer in the healthcare industry. While some degree of conflict exists, I find it somewhat amusing that doctors are placed at the top of this list.
For-Profit versus Nonprofit.
To be clear, the vast majority of hospitals in the United States are technically nonprofit institutions. Somewhere in the neighborhood of 75%, but it differs from state-to-state. So, a nonprofit by charter means they are exempt from an array of local, state and federal taxes and must perform or donate a percent of their services to the surrounding community. (Certain rural states like Alabama and Alaska have mostly government-run facilities, but for the most part nonprofits are the biggest players.)
One of the key figures during the ACA negotiations was Iowa Senator Chuck Grassley, who routinely brought up issues with respect to the nonprofit designation. As Brill writes in America’s Bitter Pill:
“Grassley had long been focused on accountability and transparency among nonprofit institutions, particularly hospitals, that enjoyed tax exemptions from the IRS. He often cited a study demonstrating that the tax-exempt hospitals provided charitable care representing less than 5% of their fast-rising revenues, which was barely higher, if at all, than the for-profit hospitals provided.”
To be clear, I’m not a fan of Grassley. But he made an important point.
Coming out of the ACA negotiations, there was a sense that profit-driven companies were unjustly rewarded with millions of new customers with little downside, and rightfully so. But again, the focus was mostly on insurance companies and Big Pharma, as well as a litany of suppliers and manufacturers for those who were really paying attention. But it seemed like hospitals were able to deflect most of the criticism because of how they’re perceived in their communities.
Being considered nonprofits gave them a certain level of cover because, after all, they’re not driven by shareholders and profits, they employ a ton of people, and sponsor fun things like little league teams. Who can hate a hospital?
But the reality is much different. An NPR feature highlights the issue with the perception versus reality of cost drivers and the role hospitals play:
“Between 2007 and 2014, hospital prices grew 42 percent. The irony is most hospitals are “nonprofit,” a status that makes them tax exempt. Many (but not all) do enough charity work to justify tax benefits, yet it’s clear nonprofit hospitals are very profitable. They funnel much of the profits into cushy salaries, shiny equipment, new buildings, and, of course, lobbying. In 2018, hospitals and nursing homes spent over $100 million on lobbying activities. And they spent about $30 million on campaign contributions. Health industries have also been funneling hefty sums into dark money groups. But their political power isn’t just the result of lobbying or electioneering. Hospitals are often the biggest employers in states and cities across America.”
Again, I want to continue to draw a key distinction between hospitals and physicians because there’s a tendency to paint them with the same brush. As Brill writes:
“Doctors—whose incomes had never increased during the recent decades of the healthcare boom the way earnings for hospital administrators, drug executives, or CT scan equipment salesmen had—were assumed to be the prime drivers of costs, and they would, therefore have to pay for driving them too high.”
Physicians are in many ways caught between a rock, a hard place and potential lawsuits. A doctor’s livelihood, particularly general practitioners, faces death by a thousand cuts. And we’ll talk more about that later. The point is to distinguish between the people working in the hospital and the people running it, and to understand the nature of the incentives behind the two categories. The absurdly complex equation that determines physician reimbursement and compensation is a muddle of forms, schedules, checkboxes and malpractice concerns that would deter most of us from even entering the field.
So, let’s go back inside the nonprofit world for a minute. Danielle Ofri from the NYU Grossman School of Medicine, wrote an op-ed in the New York Times on the eve of the pandemic about the friction within the industry regarding nonprofit hospitals. In it, she perfectly encapsulated the issue of charitable designations and what qualifies as a community benefit, things that hospitals are theoretically required to do to maintain their tax exempt status. She began with the change in the tax code in 1969 that made charitable care optional and left hospitals to “decide how to pay back that debt” to the community. Here’s Ofri:
“An analysis by Politico found that since the full Affordable Care Act coverage expansion, which brought millions more paying customers into the field, revenue in the top seven nonprofit hospitals (as ranked by U.S. News & World Report) increased by 15 percent, while charity care — the most tangible aspect of community benefit — decreased by 35 percent.
“Communities are often conflicted about the nonprofit hospitals in their midst. Many of these institutions are enormous employers — sometimes the largest employer in town — but the economic benefits do not always trickle down to the immediate neighborhoods. It is not unusual to see a stark contrast between these gleaming campuses and the disadvantaged neighborhoods that surround them.”
This is reminiscent of our discussion surrounding funding for sports stadiums that promise to bring droves of customers to a destination and revitalize communities, only to discover that fans come in, spend their money in the stadium, then leave. And these complexes often pass through the very same disadvantaged neighborhoods that Ofri highlights.
Another capitalist feature of the nonprofit hospital that will be familiar to Unf*ckers is exactly who has benefitted the most from expansion and growth. As Ofri writes:
“From 2005 to 2015, average chief executive compensation in nonprofit hospitals increased by 93 percent. Over that same period, pediatricians saw a 15 percent salary increase. Nurses got 3 percent.”
Again, these are necessary places. Brimming with hope and ideas, technology and innovation. Dedicated practitioners helping others and, yes, earning a healthy buck.
I’ve got nothing against making a buck, but remember that these were the very same practitioners who lobbied against a universal system of care or coverage, fearing that it would ultimately impact their autonomy. They got their wish. Instead of answering to the government, the medical community is subservient to a corporate class of administrators and executives from all sides looking to profit from their expertise. And the temple on high that directs the flow of information, money and policy is the hospital.
I want to finish up this chapter by once again giving it to Paul Starr, who captures the essence of the tension, conflict and bureaucracy that exists in the temple of care:
“Within the hospital, there continue to be three separate centers of authority—trustees, physicians, and administrators—posing a great puzzle to students of formal organizations. Sociologists have wanted to know why the hospital departs from the standard model of a bureaucracy in lacking a single, clear line of hierarchical authority. Economists have wanted to know what the hospital maximizes if it does not maximize profit. From the viewpoint of each discipline’s paradigm, the hospital has been an anomaly. It seems much less so historically. Hospitals began as caretaking charities under the sponsorship of wealthy patrons. Their reconstitution as centers of active medical treatment made private practitioners anxious to gain access to their precincts. The practitioners were able to gain access in America because of the financial needs of voluntary hospitals that could not adequately draw on taxes as a source of revenue. The interest of private practitioners, together with those of different ethnic and religious groups, led to the multiplication of relatively small hospitals and blocked their integration under the state. In turn, the absence of integrated management led to more competition among hospitals, more emphasis on business functions, and more administration. All of which left, instead of a single governing power, three centers of authority held together in loose alliance. Hospitals remained incompletely integrated, both as organizations and as a system of organizations—a case of blocked institutional development, a pre-capitalist institution radically changed in it functions and moral identity, but only partially transformed in its organizational structure.”
Chapter Three
Turning Doctors into Business People.
One of our core Unf*ckers, Dr. Hub from Massachusetts, shared a prescient New England Journal of Medicine editorial from 1987 by the late Arnold S. Relman. In it, Relman writes:
“Health care is becoming a business. Pressures from insurers and third-party payers for containment of costs, the growing presence of investor-owned health care corporations, and competition for market share among our overbuilt and underused hospitals are transforming the U.S. health care system into an industry. Even many of the supposedly not-for-profit voluntary hospitals have begun to behave like profit-oriented businesses.”
It’s a sentiment echoed by general practitioners all over the country who have seen their peers in other nations increase their incomes relative to their own. Practitioners who have to scratch and claw for fair reimbursements, hire internal billing coordinators and reimbursement specialists and outsource IT functions to keep up with insurance billing codes and requirements.
In contrast to this experience, specialists in medicine have seen their income soar in the past few decades. Specialists earn, on average, about a third more than GPs, with fewer administrative headaches to contend with on a daily basis. As a result of the pinch on GPs, they are forced to see more and more patients to keep level, each visit accompanied by a dizzying array of billing codes that are just the beginning of a fight for reimbursement. And, in highly populated areas, maintaining privileges at prestigious community hospitals is essential to one’s status.
A physician’s hospital affiliation, which insurance they take and efficiency scores given by insurance companies are also tantamount to a physician’s status. Nowhere in this equation is there anything about the quality and thoroughness of care. Again, Starr:
“A regime of medical austerity will test the limits of professional autonomy in the corporate system… one reason that there will be a loss of autonomy is that the organizations in which physicians work are themselves likely to become heteronomous—that is, the locus of control will be outside the immediate organization. Professional autonomy has been protected by the institutional autonomy of hospitals. In the multihospital systems, centralized planning, budgeting and personnel decisions will deprive physicians of much of the influence they are accustomed to exercise over institutional policy.”
Relman summarized the conflict between physicians and their hospital masters by warning against what he called the “businessification” of healthcare. He warned that what was once a social contract between physician and hospital would necessarily morph into a business arrangement where implicit contracts are replaced by explicit ones, collegiality gives way to policies and procedures and enforcement of behavior would be favored over collaboration in service of patient well being. Further, as Starr reflects:
“Physicians no longer have as complete control of knowledge as they formerly did; the informational asymmetries that some analysts long identified as the legitimate foundation of professional power and privilege have declined. With electronic record systems and software-generated metrics of performance, the managers of hospitals, health plans and other organizations have better information to track what doctors and other health care workers do. The means of organizational control have improved.”
Dr. Hub’s input didn’t end with just words of wisdom from Relman. He also referenced a New England Journal of Medicine article by renowned author and physician Dr. Mark Vonnegut from 2007, who opined on the nature of medicine:
“The big prize will come from creating a multitude of grading systems that rate doctors against one another, making them increasingly dependent on quality-improvement goals and payments while distracting them from patient care and making reimbursement more complicated than ever. Overhead will go through the roof. My practice already needs a full-time nurse and receptionist dedicated exclusively to quality-improvement initiatives. The incentives for getting rid of sick and poor patients will be stronger than ever.”
Chapter Four
Bring it home, Max.
There’s so much to unpack in healthcare. And we’ve only begun to scratch the surface.
The important takeaway for me when researching more about the role of the hospital is just how cold and institutional things have become. These are characteristics of industry writ large. Mega corporations where the bottom line becomes the top priority.
The biggest single takeaway, which isn’t news, is that healthcare is simply one of those things that should not be privatized and driven by profit incentives.
And that’s not to say profitable enterprises cannot exist within the structure. Healthcare workers, save for specialists in the U.S., make more in OECD nations. Furthermore, there are profitable pharmaceutical companies, insurance companies, suppliers and medical device manufacturers in other nations as well. It’s just that the relationship is flipped. In other countries, the patient’s interest is what fuels the industries. Here, it’s very much the other way around.
But again, if you are able to sustain high insurance payments relative to your income, you can avail yourself of some of the greatest care in the world here in the United States. The system is truly built for the top 10%, with the bottom 90% left in a precarious state of financial and personal well-being.
Nothing laid bare the precarious nature of America’s health system and preparedness more than our performance during the pandemic. I know we love being first, but Jesus. We were first by a mile in all negative indicators. It should be said, however, that despite our massive failure, as evidenced by mortality rates, we can’t judge the healthcare system and its capabilities independent of our politics. Nevertheless, the data are pretty bad.
The World Health Organization (WHO) parses the most reliable data and has been tracking mortality rates globally since 2005. There are gaps. Particularly in Africa, Southeast Asia and Western Pacific regions, but there is enough historical data to benchmark against when it comes to the most reliable indicator of the devastation that COVID brought to the planet, and that’s excess mortality.
Experts knew throughout the course of the pandemic—and I’m by no way suggesting that it’s over—that attributing mortality rates directly or indirectly to COVID would be tricky and political. The U.S. wasn’t the only country trying to save face or to have experts, politicians and the public fight amongst themselves.
But we have now a much clearer picture of what transpired. It’s estimated that 14.9 million deaths globally, over a two year period, are attributable to COVID, if you examine deaths over the average. In the United States, the CDC reported 1.1 million excess deaths from the norm from March of 2020 through March of 2022. That’s the benchmark that was submitted to the WHO.
In many ways, other areas caught up to the United States as the crisis wore on. And 2021 was twice as deadly as 2020 globally. India’s figures are the most controversial, as it still claims to have lost about 600,000 citizens despite the WHO calculating their excess mortality at almost 4.5 million. But our numbers are tight because our reporting processes are actually robust. Taking the WHO data at face value means that the U.S. has 4.5% of the world’s population, but reported 13.5% of COVID related deaths.
These excess mortality numbers are the final report card, America. The results are in. We allowed a profit-driven system to be manipulated by politics and killed more than a million Americans.
Where does change come from? How does it start? At one-fifth of our nation’s economic activity, it’s difficult to imagine how this gets better.
-
26 million uninsured. And that’s a record low as a percentage of the population.
-
Tens of millions more underinsured.
-
A million bankruptcies a year due to medical costs.
-
Increasing mortality because of a mishandled pandemic; one we drew up the blueprint to handle, but didn’t follow.
-
Health outcomes that are no longer comparable to OECD member nations that pay half of what we do per capita on healthcare.
To answer the question of how this changes, it should be evident that change cannot come from private industry or the political class. As Nelson Lichtenstein observes in his book State of the Union:
“In Canada and in most of Europe, where systems of universal health insurance were funded out of general tax revenue, labor fought its health-care battles at the ballot box and in the parliamentary committee chamber, thus reserving its picket-line clout for wage and workplace issues closer to the immediate interests of its working members.”
There’s only one Bernie Sanders in the Senate. There are only a handful of AOCs, Omars, Blumenauers and Porters in Congress.
We simply don’t have the numbers in government to make meaningful change. When Obama was presented with a mandate from the people and had the numbers on his side to push through reform, it gave the false impression that he had the ability to finally pursue true universal coverage. But that was never even discussed.
We recently covered the student debt crisis in great detail. But we didn’t touch on the overwhelming costs of medical school. Sure, there are certain programs that allow for free medical training. There are teaching hospitals that will forgive medical debt over time, if you practice in their system. There’s another term for that. Indentured servitude. It’s yet another sign of madness—and unique to us, once again—that we would encumber doctors and nurses in this country with such extraordinary debt that they become immediately beholden to the system and the cycle of billable hours and billing codes.
I can think of no more appropriate name for a form that runs the entire cost system in this country than the chargemaster.
Medicare for All is considered a given for seniors. But extending it to 55 causes too much harm to insurance companies? You can thank Joe Lieberman for that. Extending it to all suddenly becomes socialism?
Exactly one-half of the Senate is 65 or older. Can they not see the artificial madness of this cutoff date?
In the absence of true reform, we will continue on a path of half measures and backroom deals, with private companies whose interests are ahead of the patient and physician. In private industry, revenue must always go up. Always. So, if the entire system is scaffolded by private companies that demand more every year, the cost inputs to the system will always increase, thereby necessitating more subsidies, more deficits or both. And these can come from either the government or the population.
Right now, the Biden administration is splitting the difference and offering some relief, but costs and increases are inevitable, and this tenuous partnership with the current administration is only as good as its grip on power.
Every episode we do is an adventure. An exploration. A puzzle. This one might be the most frustrating because the answer is right in front of us, and yet out of reach. I know we all want easy solutions and straightforward answers, so here you go.
The answer is Medicare for All.
A combination of perhaps the French and German systems. A system entirely funded through taxation that brings everyone under coverage, still allows for the existence of private insurance for premium care and electives, pays healthcare workers extremely well and controls cost inputs. And the only way to achieve this is by passing the For the People Act to get money out of politics. That’s the most straightforward answer I’ll ever give you. Medicare for All is attainable if we eliminate the power of the special interests and give labor the ability to organize freely.
So, in the absence of this miracle, we’re back to half measures. And on this, there are a few that make sense:
-
Fully subsidized medical school. If that’s too hard, then debt at federal fund rates and full forgiveness after five or ten years in practice.
-
Make pharmaceutical advertising illegal. We didn’t get too far into this, but we have a very big problem here. I’ll save this for another day.
-
Medicare enrollment at 60. Fight to bring the age down with the argument that the government fucked up the pandemic and increased our mortality rates for the first time since 1926. And we still don’t know the long-term effects of COVID, not to mention those with Long-Haul COVID. This is a just fight that would bring millions more into full coverage.
-
Expand the subsidy range calculation to bring more lower-middle income households into the fold on the exchanges.
-
Create a panel to evaluate the nonprofit status of the 5,000 or more hospitals that claim tax exempt status, and make this a higher bar. Hospitals should be required to participate in pilot programs that fund local municipalities. It’s no longer enough to put your logo on the back of the youth softball league jerseys and sponsor a local concert series at the town bandshell. Robbing communities of badly needed tax dollars contributes to a reduction in local services and education, both of which contribute to health outcomes.
-
This same panel should evaluate what qualifies as healthcare spending, so the big insurance companies can stop gaming the system and adhere to the 80% rule.
But what do I know? Tell you what. I’ll give the final word to Dr. Mark Vonnegut, who sent this note to us:
“Patients pay for everything, including the many attempts to “fix” healthcare delivery, all of which have failed miserably. 50 years of trying have produced exactly zero instances in which Costs have been controlled or Quality improved. Every innovation, the HMO model itself, QI [Quality Improvement], copays, deductibles, open and closed panels, LOS [Length of Stay], DRG [Diagnosis-Related Group], PPOs [Preferred Provider Organizations], withholds, enhanced reimbursement, EMR [Electronic Medical Records] and on and on do exactly what not covering pre existing conditions did; under-treating those who need care and over-treating those who don’t. Each and every one of these innovations hurts public and individual health, increasing the cost of insurance. It’s like a pyramid scheme and/or protection racket.
“We actually know how to make medical care better and less expensive. To deal with COVID, we dropped copayments and deductibles, improving the quality of care and public health while saving patients and their families hundreds of millions of dollars. While it’s relatively easy to attack socialism, big government and liberals in general, it’s much harder to argue for copayments and that it’s OK to hurt patients. It’s easy to show how these innovations have and continue to do harm, something we promised to not do.
“We can also, if necessary, use pilot programs and robust data to support the fact that eliminating copayments lowers costs and increases quality. We can then apply the same logic and math to deductibles, PPOs and the rest of the alphabet soup.
“50+% of a hospital’s unnecessary care and overhead is directly attributable to insurance and other profit driven mandates. We’ve lost 40+% of our hospitals and 85% of our community doctors.
“Most innovations in healthcare delivery were made part of healthcare without legislation and can be unmade part of care the same way as was done to respond to COVID. There are no instances where copayments or QI etc., etc., improves anyone’s care or lowers anyone’s costs. A great deal of the mess we find ourselves is attributable to the silence, cowardice and short term greed of doctors in general. With a little education and prodding, it’s not impossible that they can grow half the balls demonstrated by nurses when they strike for better care and better staffing rather than a bigger slice of the profit pie.”
The top 10% of the nation can afford the very best healthcare in the world. For the rest, it’s a scramble and a pressure. We’ve designed a system built around a network of for-profit corporations that benefit whether health outcomes improve or deteriorate. And remember, 90% of those companies are owned by the same 10%.
The power is in the hands of labor and the working class.
Stop protecting premiums over patients.
They made this a class issue, so let them deal with the consequence when the working class rises up against them.
Here endeth the lesson.
Sources & Resources
Resources
-
The New York Times: Big Changes Are Coming for Health Care Costs
-
Health System Tracker: National Health Spending Explorer
-
CMS.gov: NHE Fact Sheet
-
Milton Friedman: How to Cure Health Care
-
Medtronic: Annual Report
-
Abbott Laboratories: Annual Report
-
Stryker: 2021 Comprehensive Report
-
HCA Healthcare, Inc: Annual Report
-
Fierce Healthcare: Kaiser Permanente reports $8.1B net profit in 2021 despite shrinking operating income
-
UHS: Annual Report
-
UnitedHealth Group: Annual Report
-
Humana: 2021 Annual Report
-
Anthem, Inc: Annual Report
-
Pfizer: Annual Report
-
Merck & Co: Annual Report
-
AbbVie Inc: Annual Report
-
CNBC: The wealthiest 10% of Americans own a record 89% of all U.S. stocks
-
The New York Times: U.S. Life Expectancy Falls Again in ‘Historic’ Setback
-
Health System Tracker: How does health spending in the U.S. compare to other countries?
-
The Atlantic: Did a Conservative Think Tank Really Invent the Individual Mandate?
-
The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation: The Burden of Medical Debt: Results from the Kaiser Family Foundation/New York Times
-
UnitedHealth Group: Annual Report
-
Humana: 2021 Annual Report
-
Anthem, Inc: Annual Report
-
National Association of Insurance Commissioners: U.S. Health Insurance Industry Analysis Report
-
OECD.stat: Health Care Resources: Hospitals
-
EOS Surfaces: Types of Hospitals in the US
-
American Hospital Association: Fast Facts on U.S. Hospitals, 2022
-
Becker’s Hospital Review: 82 Physician-Owned Hospitals to Know
-
AMA Journal of Ethics: Physician-Owned Hospitals and Self-Referral
-
NPR’s Planet Money: How Non-Profit Hospitals Are Driving Up The Cost Of Health Care
-
Weatherby Healthcare: Physician salary report 2022: Physician income rising again
-
The New York Times: Why Are Nonprofit Hospitals So Highly Profitable?
-
Hub’s List: A data-based biweekly newsletter of medical fun facts
-
The New England Journal of Medicine: Practicing Medicine in the New Business Climate
-
The New England Journal of Medicine: Is Quality Improvement Improving Quality? A View from the Doctor's Office
-
CNN: 2 charts that show just how old this Congress actually is
-
The Commonwealth Fund: International Health Care System Profiles- France
-
Germany Visa: Health Insurance in Germany- The German Healthcare System
-
Congress.gov: H.R.1 For the People Act
-
NASHP: Can We Please Stop Fixating on Hospital Chargemasters?
-
The Lever: Where Did The Public Option Go?
Book Love
-
Steven Brill: America's Bitter Pill: Money, Politics, Backroom Deals, and the Fight to Fix Our Broken Healthcare System
-
Nelson Lichtenstein: State of the Union: A Century of American Labor
-
Mark Vonnegut: The Heart of Caring: A Life in Pediatrics
Pod Love
-
Congressional Dish: CD255: Pharmacy Benefit Managers (PBMs)
Image Source
- Ted Eytan, CC BY-SA 2.0, via Wikimedia Commons. Changes were made.